Project on Defense Alternatives Briefing Memo #35
10 December 2005
Carl Conetta
In its National Strategy for Victory in Iraq
the Bush administration recognizes that the key to defusing the
insurgency is drawing the Sunni Arab community into the political
process. And it correctly sees that this requires "inclusive
institutions that offer power-sharing mechanisms and minority
protections." As the strategy notes: such institutions would
"demonstrate to disaffected Sunnis that they have influence and the
ability to protect their interests in a democratic Iraq."
Unfortunately, the administration finds it difficult to apply this
precept where it would matter most: in the election process.
The
procedures for the December 2005 election of Iraq’s Council of
Representatives, which will govern for four years, puts Sunni Arab
areas at a distinct disadvantage. It virtually guarantees that Sunni
Arabs will be under-represented in government. This is no way to "win
hearts and minds" or to erode support for the insurgency.
The
15 December election will fill the 275 seats of Iraq’s national
assembly (now officially called the "Council of Representatives"). Of
these seats, 230 are allocated among Iraq’s 18 provinces to be filled
through local contests. But the allocation to provinces does not
correspond with their relative population size – as is the case in the
United States with House of Representative seats. Instead, the
allocation accords with the relative numbers of people who registered to vote in the 30 January 2005 election
– an election that Sunni Arabs boycotted. Using these voter
registration rolls (which were completed in late 2004) as a basis for
allocating assembly seats is not a democratic "best practice", as
explained below. Nor does it serve political stability. And, as it so
happens, the procedure disfavors Sunnis, while favoring Kurds.
About
24 percent of Iraq’s population resides in the four Sunni Arab-majority
provinces – but the present election system allots them only 20 percent
of the 230 assigned seats. (See Table 1.) By contrast, the three
Kurdish provinces, with approximately 13 percent of the country’s
population, receive 15 percent of the seats. Thus, the system boosts
the power of the Kurdish provinces by four or five seats, while
clipping that of the Sunni Arab region by as many as eight. The system
also marginally reduces the sway of the southern Shia provinces, while
increasing that of Baghdad and At Ta’mim (Kirkuk) province. (At Ta’mim,
too, is a Kurdish power center).
Turning
to the remaining 45 assembly seats, which are not allotted to
provinces: These are called "national" or "compensatory" seats. But the
allocation process for these will worsen the under-representation of
Sunnis, not repair it.
Table 1: Iraqi Governorate Population and Assigned Council Seats
|
Governorates (Provinces)
| Percent of Voters Rejecting Constitution |
Population (000s) |
Percent of Population |
Assigned Council Seats |
Percent of Assigned Seats |
Mixed
|
|
|
|
|
|
Baghdad
|
22.3
|
6554.
|
24.15
|
59
|
25.65
|
At Ta'mim (Possible Kurd Majority)
|
37.09
|
854.
|
3.15
|
9
|
3.91
|
Kurdish majority
|
|
|
|
|
|
Dahuk
|
0.87
|
472.
|
1.74
|
7
|
3.04
|
Arbil (Erbil)
|
0.64
|
1392.
|
5.13
|
13
|
5.65
|
As Sulaymaniyah
|
1.04
|
1716.
|
6.32
|
15
|
6.52
|
Subtotal
|
|
3580.
|
13.2
|
35
|
15.2
|
Sunni Arab majority
|
|
|
|
|
|
Al Anbar
|
96.9
|
1329.
|
4.9
|
9
|
3.91
|
Salah ad Din
|
81.75
|
1119.
|
4.12
|
8
|
3.48
|
Ninawa (Nineveh)
|
55.08
|
2554.
|
9.41
|
19
|
8.26
|
Diyala
|
48.73
|
1418.
|
5.23
|
10
|
4.35
|
Subtotal
|
|
6420.
|
23.66
|
46
|
20.0
|
Shia Arab majority
|
|
|
|
|
|
Babil
|
5.44
|
1493.
|
5.5
|
11
|
4.78
|
Al Basrah
|
3.98
|
1797.
|
6.62
|
16
|
6.96
|
Al Karbala
|
3.42
|
787.
|
2.9
|
6
|
2.60
|
Maysan
|
2.21
|
763.
|
2.81
|
7
|
3.04
|
Al Muthanna
|
1.35
|
555.
|
2.04
|
5
|
2.17
|
An Najaf
|
4.18
|
978.
|
3.6
|
8
|
3.48
|
Al Qadisyah
|
3.32
|
912.
|
3.36
|
8
|
3.48
|
Dhi Qar
|
2.85
|
1472.
|
5.42
|
12
|
5.22
|
Wasit
|
4.3
|
971.
|
3.58
|
8
|
3.48
|
Subtotal
|
|
9728.
|
35.83
|
81
|
35.12
|
Total
|
|
27136.
|
99.99
|
230
|
100.00
|
Population
figures are from: Ministry of Planning and Development Cooperation,
Republic of Iraq, and the United Nations Development Program, Iraq Living Conditions Survey 2004, Volume 1: Tabulation Report (Baghdad, 2005). Allocation of council of representative seats can be found in Independent Electoral Commission of Iraq, FAQ 4: Council of Representatives Elections,
http://www.ieciraq.org/final%20cand/FAQ_Council%20of%20Representatives_En.pdf
|
The "national" or "compensatory" seats are to be distributed in two steps:
-
The first will award seats to those parties who did not gain enough
votes for a seat in any province, but whose national totals surpass a
certain threshold. This favors parties with shallow but broad roots.
-
The second step will allocate the remaining seats to parties in accord
with their proportion of the total national vote. This step will favor
parties that draw their strength from provinces with above-average
voter turnout. In essence, it rewards those regions that manage a high
voter turnout.
In
some electoral systems – such as the American one - regional or "state"
differences in voter turnout would not affect the degree of a region’s
representation in government. But they do in Iraq.
One
important factor affecting turnout is security. So we might also say
that the measure punishes those areas suffering security problems. And,
as we know, the incidence of terrorist violence and military operations
is much higher in Sunni areas than elsewhere.
Regarding
security differentials: In a representative period, 94 percent of all
insurgent attacks occurred in just six provinces: the four Sunni Arab
majority areas, Baghdad, and At Ta’mim (Kirkuk). (These six contain 50
percent of the Iraqi population.) According to the US Defense
Department’s October 2005 report on Iraq, the incidence of daily
attacks per 100,000 people was above 1.8 and 1.6 in Al Anbar and Salah
ad Din, respectively, during the period from 29 August to 16 September.
The level was about 0.4 in Baghdad, At Ta’mim, Ninawa, and Diyala. In
Babil it was 0.12. Elsewhere it was one-third or less of the level in
Babil and only about 2 percent the level in Al Anbar.
In
sum, the nature of the Iraqi election system and the obvious realities
that Iraqis face on the ground allow us (and Iraq’s Sunni Arabs) to
conclude before a single vote is cast that Sunni-based parties will win
fewer seats on 15 December than the size of the Sunni community might
suggest, while the Kurdish parties will walk away with more.
Deforming the State
The
procedure for the December election actually shows some improvements
over that employed last January – which may be one reason that Sunni
Arabs are more willing to participate this time around. At the same
time, the new system carries forward and codifies some of the errors of
the past. This will weaken the legitimacy of the Iraqi state as it
tries to tackle divisive issues in the years ahead.
The
persisting shortfalls in the Iraq system are best understood if we look
back to the January 2005 election and work our way forward. The
procedure in the January election did not allocate any assembly seats
to provinces. All were decided in a contest that treated the entire
country as a single electoral district. Treating the entire country as
a single electoral district has the effect of pitting different regions
against each other in a never-ending fight over baseline representation
in government. It is as if every congressional election in America gave
the states an opportunity to tear seats away from each other. The
problem is made worse in Iraq by the fact that ethno-religious groups
tend to concentrate geographically. Thus, the regional fight over basic
representation takes on an ethnic hue, with each group always
threatening to relatively disenfranchise the other.
By
contrast, in actual US domestic practice, congressional elections do
not affect the degree of representation afforded each state. Indeed,
the "single national district" approach is so divisive that the
American colonists would probably have found it impossible to form a
nation on this basis. When sectoral differences are acute or when
suspicions run high, this approach is more likely to rip a nation apart
than to unify it.
Some
framers of the original Iraqi system – notably the UN consultants –
thought that by also adopting proportional representation they could
ensure fair treatment of all ethnic and religious groups. And this
might have produced a fair result – if Iraq’s various communities were
distributed evenly across the country or if there were no regional
differences that might affect voter turnout.
However,
in Iraq, the geographic concentration of ethnic and religious groups is
a bedrock reality. And there are numerous factors that can cause
regional differences in voter turnout rates that have nothing to do
with population size. These include differences of climate and weather,
terrain, urban-rural balance, population density, and age demographics
as well as differences in the local management of elections and voter
registration.
As
noted above, the security environment has an especially strong affect
on voter turnout. Thus, those communities and regions suffering most
from security problems are disfavored by this system. This was the key
reason Sunni Arabs thought the election to be unfair and one reason,
aside from fear, that so many boycotted it.
A
more democratic approach would allocate assembly seats to provinces in
accord with their population size. This would guarantee baseline
representation to all regions regardless of turnout. Electoral
competition then could become a contest between political tendencies,
rather than ethnic regions. Sunni, Shia, and Kurdish areas all would
gain representation relative to their population size. Aside from
defusing some of the ethnic tension associated with the election
process, this approach would make it possible to selectively postpone
elections in provinces plagued by severe violence or natural
catastrophes.
Tying
assembly seats to localities has other benefits as well. It ensures a
closer connection between voters and their representatives – especially
if prospective candidates must meet residency requirements. And it
makes it easier for voters to know the candidates, make informed
choices, and hold their elected representatives accountable. Purely as
a matter of building confidence in the new government, Iraqis need to
see their local men and women elected to office.
In
the coming election, the "single national district" system applies only
to the 45 national seats. And this indicates progress. But the
inequities of the January 2005 election persist in other ways as well.
As noted above, those 230 assembly seats that now have been allocated
to provinces correspond to voter registration rolls from late 2004,
when the Sunni boycott was in full swing.
The
boycott aside: Many of the same factors that can suppress voter turnout
– such as security problems – also negatively affect voter registration
rates. So, in this regard too, the differences between provinces do not
reflect their relative population size.
As
a result, the national assembly or "council of representatives" that
will rule Iraq for the critical next four years will partially reflect
the problems and inequalities that plagued the January 2005 election
process. That election will live on in the Iraq body politic like a bad
gene.
Conclusion
What
difference would it make to adopt a system that ties all assembly seats
to provinces based on their populations? It would probably entail a
structural shift of four or five percent of assembly seats to parties
popular with Sunni Arabs. More significantly, in all regions and
communities, it would favor candidates with deep local roots, while
disfavoring expatriates of all stripes. Thus, the political fortunes of
leaders like the Shia cleric Moqtada Sadr would advance. All in all, it
would probably produce a national assembly with a notably stronger
oppositionist temper. And this the Bush administration might find
difficult to swallow.
References
George W. Bush, National Strategy for Victory in Iraq (Washington DC: White House, 30 November 2005),
http://www.whitehouse.gov/infocus/iraq/iraq_national_strategy_20051130.pdf
Electoral Commission of Iraq, Certification of the Constitutional Referendum Final Results (Baghdad: 25 October 2005),
http://www.ieciraq.org/final%20cand/20051102%20Certified%20Referendum%20Results%20English.pdf
US Department of Defense, Report to Congress: Measuring Stability and Security in Iraq (Washington DC: DOD, October 2005),
http://www.pentagon.mil/pubs/20051013_publication_OSSRF.pdf
Electoral Commission of Iraq, FAQ 4: Council of Representatives Elections,
http://www.ieciraq.org/final%20cand/FAQ_Council%20of%20Representatives_En.pdf
Ministry of Planning and Development Cooperation, Republic of Iraq, and the United Nations Development Program, Iraq Living Conditions Survey 2004, Volume 1: Tabulation Report (Baghdad: 2005).
Citation:
Carl Conetta, Masque of Democracy: Iraqi Election System Still
Disfavors Sunni Arabs, Favors Kurds, Cambridge, MA: Commonwealth
Institute Project on Defense
Alternatives Briefing Memo #35, 10 December 2005.
http://www.comw.org/pda/0512bm35.html
|